Description

This repository has a short literature review regarding social discount rates and individual discount rates. Next, it shows tables containing:

  • Techno-economic parameters for generation technologies.
  • Fuel prices
  • List of future investments in electricity generation.
  • References

Discount rates

Generation technologies usually have a long useful lifetime (e.g., hydropower, thermal power plants). In terms of expenditures, generation projects face costs in the evaluation process, at the construction phase, in operation/generation, and even during decommissioning. These costs occur at different times during the useful life of such power plants. In this regard, it is crucial to select the proper discount rate if a government or private investor is likely to invest in long life and high capital-intensive energy projects in the supply industry.

Concerning discount rates, one has to differentiate between the financial discount rates and the discount rate to analyze long-term environmental considerations and welfare. The first one, a financial discount, deals from an investment perspective and its financial cash flows. In contrast, the second is used in the evaluation of a social welfare function [1]. The first one is the one that will be used in this paper. Additionally, the discount rate is a term referred to as the cost of capital. Both terms are often interchangeable; yet, these are different. A discount rate is a rate used for discounting cash flows, and a cost of capital is the rate of return from an investment [2].

Studies by Garcia-Gusano et. al. [3] and Goulder et. Al [1] stated the importance of discount rates in optimization models. In this model, we used different discount rates for evaluating combinations of policy decisions, future investments in a series of scenarios to test the sensitivity of generation technologies to discount rates. For instance, we use global or social discount rates (SDR) to assess the total cost from a public perspective. Also, individual or hurdle rates (HR) reflecting a private investor’s expected return.

Social discount rates

Social discount rates (SDR) are used in cost-benefit analysis in long-term government projects by discounting future cash flows to obtain a present value. One of the most challenging factors in a cost-benefit analysis for public investments is selecting the appropriate social discount rate [4,5]. Several authors have analyzed and discussed the advantages and disadvantages of different methods for determining the SDR or developed surveys to collect data from experts in selecting SDR [6]. Yet, there is no consensus on the proper process of how to set a suitable SDR.

This lack of consensus is exemplified in the work undertaken by Zhuang et al. [7]. This study found that there are significant differences in selecting the discount rate in different countries. According to this, developed countries have lower social discount rates from 3% to 7%; however, developing counties were found to apply higher discount rates from 8% to 15%. Another example of such differences is when countries use constant discount rates while others use a declining discount rate [8]. A common practice is that government institutions decide the SDR. For example, the UK set a discount rate at 3.5%, and this rate declines overtime for projects longer than 30 years [9].

Development agencies can also assess the SDR for a specific country. For example, the World Bank often applies discount rates from 10% to 12% for developing countries [10]. The level of the rate depends on factors such as availability of capital, public funds, rate of interest of borrowing, and alternative approaches [11]. A common practice is to undertake projects as long as the rate of return is higher than the cost of borrowing.

Specific discount rates-hurdle rates

The private sector is also a way to fund energy projects. As such, from a private investor perspective, the cost of capital is mostly calculated by using the capital asset pricing model (\(CAPM\)) as seen in Eq. 1. \[E[r] = r_f + \beta.(E[r_m]-r_f)\] Where \(E[r]\) is the investor expected rate of return or cost of capital, \(r_f\) is the risk free rate of return and \(E[r_m]\) is the market risk premium. The expression \((E[r_m ]-r_f)\) is the market risk premium modified by β, which is a measure of the systematic risk. In other words, an investor would require a rate of return that considers a risk free rate and compensation due to the risk of taking such investment. As stated earlier, the CAPM model would solve the issue of systematic risk, which is inherent to the market itself; thus, unavoidable. Nevertheless, the investor would solve another issue, the unsystematic risk, which is unique for each project, by diversifying the portfolio.

A second method used in project evaluation and viability is the weighted average cost of capital (\(WACC\)) Eq.2.

\[ WACC = r_e.E + r_d.(1-T_c).D\]
Where the cost of equity and debt are \(r_e\), \(r_d\), and \(T_c\) is the corporate tax. \(E\) and \(D\) are equity and debt ratio, respectively. Both the \(WACC\) and \(CAPM\) generally are methods used to calculate the cost of capital. However, there is high uncertainty, which is the preferred method for countries and private investors. This is due to differences in calculation methods, input data, and mostly in developing countries [12].

According to Khatib [11], the use of the \(WACC\) as a cost of capital is erroneous when comparing projects that have different risks. As such, \(WACC\) is the rate at which a firm is expected to pay to all sources of financing (e.g., equity, debt), not a rate of return. Unlike Khatib, Berk et al. [2] showed that an investor/firm could use the \(WACC\) as the cost of capital under two assumptions. First, the market risk of the project should be similar to the average market risk of the firm’s investments. Second, investor/firm should maintain a constant debt-equity ratio. In a similar study conducted by Villareal et al. [13], it was proposed a modified methodology in which both methods, \(WACC\) and \(CAPM\), showed consistency in results.

Regarding specific rates, Helms et al. [14] found an average cost of capital of 8% in Europe for utility companies; yet, a 5% can be added as a standard practice to obtain a hurdle rate. The most relevant reports showing discount rates or hurdle rates for generation technologies were developed for the Committee on Climate Change and the Department of Energy and Climate Change [15,16]. Both reports used an extended \(CAPM\) framework for determining hurdle rates. Finally, a study in Europe carried out by Steinbach et. Al. [17] for the Building Performance Institute Europe (BPIE) identified SDR and individual hurdle rates for several policies in different countries.

Specific discount in Osemosys

The implemetation of specific discount rates in Osemosys is as follows

The addition of a new parameter for individual discount rates DiscountRateIdv[r,t]. This parameter allows the modeler to enter specific discount rates for each technology. When DiscountRateIdv[r,t] is not stated in the data file, the default discount rate is set to be the DiscountRate[r] or a global discount rate.

param DiscountRateIdv{r in REGION, t in TECHNOLOGY}, default DiscountRate[r];

An extra parameter is added to the code, the Capital Recovery Factor (CRD). The \(CRF\) (Eq. 3) allows calculating a series of equal payments, from the Capital Investment or a lump sum, spread over the operational life of a generation technology. The formula for the CRF is represented as: \[\frac{1-(1+DiscountRateIdv[r,t])^{-1}}{1-(1+DiscountRateIdv[r,t])^{-n}}\] Where \(n\) is operational life of a generation technology.

The representation in Osemosys as GNU MathProg language is:

param CapitalRecoveryFactor{r in REGION, t in TECHNOLOGY} := (1 - (1 + DiscountRateIdv[r,t])^(-1))/(1 - (1 + DiscountRateIdv[r,t])^(-(OperationalLife[r,t])));

The final parameter implemented in the code is the \(PvAnnuity\). This factor allows calculating the present value of the all-individual payments (calculated by the CRF) in the investment year at the global discount rate DiscountRate[r] as seen in Eq.4. \[\frac{(1-(1+DiscountRate[r])^{-n}).(1+DiscountRate[r])}{DiscountRate[r]}\] Where \(n\) is operational life of a generation technology. The representation in Osemosys as GNU MathProg language is:

param PvAnnuity{r in REGION, t in TECHNOLOGY} := (1 - (1 + DiscountRate[r])^(-(OperationalLife[r,t]))) * (1 + DiscountRate[r]) / DiscountRate[r];

Finally, the Capital Investment is updated by the \(CRF\) and the \(PvAnnuity\) factos as follows:

CC1_UndiscountedCapitalInvestment{r in REGION, t in TECHNOLOGY, y in YEAR}: CapitalCost[r,t,y] * NewCapacity[r,t,y] * CapitalRecoveryFactor[r,t] * PvAnnuity[r,t] = CapitalInvestment[r,t,y];

Technoeconomic assumptions

Table A 1. Techno economic assumption for the Ecuador’s model.

Technologies Capital Cost Fixed Cost Variable Cost Life Time Construction time Capacity factor Source
(USD/kW) (USD/kW) (USD/MWh) years years %
Biomass 1 4400 80.0 4 40 3 varies [18]
CCGT 2 1100 10.9 3.4 40 2 varies [19]
Geothermal 3633 35.0 2 40 3 80 [20,21]
Hydro_L 3 1500 31.0 2 80 6 50 [18]
Hydro_M 4 2000 50.0 2 80 4 50
Hydro_S 5 3000 120.0 2 80 3 50
ICE_biogas 2175 43.5 0.005 40 2 Varies [18]
ICE_FO (fuel oil) 1215 10.0 10 40 2 Varies [22]
ICE_res (residue) 1215 10.0 10 40 2 Varies [22]
Solar PV 1210 21.0 - 25 1 16 [18,23]
Steam_FO 1021 50.0 10 40 2 varies [22,24]
Wind_pot 6,7 1549 30.0 - 25 2 25 [18,23]

1Fluidized bed (FB) boiler. 2 Combined cycle gas turbine. 3,4,5 Large, medium, and small-scale average capacity factor. 6 Average capacity factor and wind speed higher 7.5 ms-1. 7 Wind potential, adapted from Projected Costs of Generating Electricity 2015 [8]. In the model, we assumed an even expenditure of capital/overnight cost for each year of construction.

Table A 2. Fuel prices

Fuel Price (USD) Unit Model period Source
Diesel 0.90 Gallon 2018-2050 [26]
Fuel oil1 0.62 Gallon 2018-2050
Residue2 0.41 Gallon 2018-2050
Natural gas3 2.75 MMBTU4 2018-2050 , [27]
Natural gas (import) 3.75 MMBTU 2030-2050 [28]

1 Average value from two refinery facilities. 2 Residue for electricity generation is a mixture of 80 percent residue and 20 percent solvent (diesel 2). 3 Price for electricity generation. 4 Million Btu

Table A 3.Future investments

List of future capacity investments for BAU, SDR, and HR scenarios

year Power Plant Capacity (MW) Annual average energy (GWh) Type Source
2020 San Jose de Minas 6.0 40.0 RoRa [29,30]
Chorillos 4.0 27.4 RoR [31,32]
Huascachaca 50.0 122.6 Wind onshore [33]
2021 Piatua 30.0 172.0 RoR [34]
Chalpi grande 7.6 33.2 RoR [35]
La Magdalena 20.0 114.0 RoR [36]
Ibarra Fugua 30.0 207.6 RoR [37]
Sabanilla 30.0 194.0 RoR [38]
Maravilla 8.2 61.6 RoR [39]
2022 El Salto 30.0 247.0 RoR [40]
Quijos 50.0 355.0 RoR [41]
Soldados Yanuncay 7.0 30.6 Storage Hydro [42]
El Aromo 200.0 280.0 Solar PV Utility [43]
CCGT 400.0 - Gas turbine
2023 Yanuncai 14.6 63.9 Cascade system – Hydro-Soldados [42]
CCb 600.0 - Gas turbine
Villonaco II y III 100.0 - Wind on-shore [44]
2025 Cardenillo 596.0 3355.8 Storage Hydro [45]
2026 Geothermal 150.0 Geothermal
Santiago I, IIc 1200.0 4966.0 Storage Hydro [46,47]
2027 Santiago III, IVc 1200.0 4966.0 Storage Hydro

a RoR: Run of the river. b Combined cycle gas turbine. c in 2019, the Ministry of Energy announced that the initial project was overestimated, the final capacity should decrease from 3.6 GW to 2.4 GW.

GitHub repositories

Forked from OSeMOSYS/OSeMOSYS_GNU_MathProg. This repository has the implementation of individual discount rate.

Additional data for residual power plants or installed power plants.

References

[1] Goulder LH, Iii RCW. The choice of discount rate for climate change policy evaluation 2012. https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010007812500248.
[2] Berk J, DeMarzo P, Harford J, Ford G, Mollica V, Finch N. Fundamentals of Corporate Finance. 2nd Editio. Pearson Higher Education AU; 2013.
[3] García-Gusano D, Espegren K, Lind A, Kirkengen M. The role of the discount rates in energy systems optimisation models. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2016;59:56–72. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.RSER.2015.12.359.
[4] Moore MA, Boardman AE, Vining AR. Social Discount Rates for Seventeen Latin American Countries: Theory and Parameter Estimation. Public Financ Rev 2020;48:43–71. https://doi.org/10.1177/1091142119890369.
[5] Burgess DF, Zerbe RO. The most appropriate discount rate. J Benefit-Cost Anal 2013;4:391–400. https://doi.org/10.1515/jbca-2013-0016.
[6] Drupp M, Freeman M, Groom B, Nesje F. Discounting disentangled: an expert survey on the determinants of the long-term social discount rate. 2015.
[7] Zhuang J, Liang Z, Lin T, De Guzman F. Theory and Practice in the Choice of Social Discount Rate for Cost-Benefit Analysis: A Survey. 2007.
[8] Roche J. Intergenerational equity and social discount rates: what have we learned over recent decades? Int J Soc Econ 2015. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJSE-07-2015-0193.
[9] HM Treasury. The Green Book: appraisal and evaluation in central government. 2018.
[10] Bonzanigo L, Kalra N. Making Informed Investment Decisions in an Uncertain World A Short Demonstration. 2014.
[11] Khatib H. Economic evaluation of projects in the electricity supply industry. 3rd Editio. IET; 2014.
[12] Jacobs J, van Vuuren G. The role of cost of capital in regulatory capital discrepancies among developing countries. South African J Econ Manag Sci 2015;18:84–104. https://doi.org/10.17159/2222-3436/2015/v18n1a7.
[13] Villarreal JE, Córdoba MJ. A Consistent Methodology for the Calculation of the Cost of Capital in Emerging Markets. SSRN Electron J 2012. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1663845.
[14] Helms T, Salm S, Wüstenhagen R. Investor-Specific Cost of Capital and Renewable Energy Investment Decisions. In: Donovan CW, editor. Renew. Energy Financ. Funding Futur. Energy. 2nd ed., 2020, p. 85–111.
[15] Committee on Climate Change. Discount rates for low carbon and renewable generation technologies. 2011.
[16] Department of Energy and Climate Change. Electricity Generation Costs and Hurdle Rates Lot 1: Hurdle Rates update for Generation Technologies 2015.
[17] Steinbach J, Isi F, Staniaszek D. Discount rates in energy system analysis Discussion Paper. 2015.
[18] IRENA. Renewable Power Generation Costs in 2017. Abu Dhabi: 2018.
[19] EIA. Assumptions to the Annual Energy Outlook 2017. 2017.
[20] ESMAP. Geothermal handbook: Planning and FinancinG Power Generation. 2012.
[21] IRENA. Geothermal Power: Technology Brief. Abu Dhabi: 2017.
[22] LAZARD. LAZARD’s levelized cos t of energy analysis. 2017.
[23] IRENA. Renewable Power Generation Costs in 2018. Abu Dhabi: 2019.
[24] EIA. Construction costs for most power plant types have fallen in recent years. Today in Energy 2017.
https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=31912 (accessed July 3, 2020).
[25] IEA-NEA. Projected Costs of Generating Electricity 2015 Edition. OECD PUBLICATIONS; 2015.
[26] ARCH. PRECIOS COMBUSTIBLES – Agencia de Regulación y Control Hidrocarburífero n.d. https://www.controlhidrocarburos.gob.ec/precios-combustibles/ (accessed March 3, 2020).
[27] Pacheco M. Ecuador importará gas natural para cubrir la demanda. El Comer 2018. https://www.elcomercio.com/actualidad/ecuador-importacion-gasnatural-demanda-inversion.html (accessed July 3, 2020).
[28] IEA. World Energy Outlook 2019 2019. https://doi.org/10.1787/caf32f3b-en.
[29] ARCONEL. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico San José de Minas – ARCONEL n.d.
https://www.regulacionelectrica.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-san-jose-de-minas/ (accessed February 25, 2020). [30] UNFCCC. CDM: San José de Minas Hydroelectric Project 2008. https://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/DB/SGS-UKL1207676097.8/view (accessed February 25, 2020).
[31] ARCONEL. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico Chorrillos – ARCONEL n.d. https://www.regulacionelectrica.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-chorrillos/ (accessed February 25, 2020).
[32] SENPLADES. Proyectos emblematicos en Zamora Chinchipe 2014.
[33] ELECAUSTRO. Proyecto Central Eólica Minas de Huascachaca 2019.
http://www.elecaustro.com.ec/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=65&Itemid=457 (accessed February 25, 2020).
[34] ARCONEL. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico Piatúa n.d. https://www.regulacionelectrica.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-coca-codo-sinclair/ (accessed February 25, 2020).
[35] ARCONEL. Proyecto hidroeléctrico Chalpi Grande n.d. https://www.regulacionelectrica.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-chalpi-grande/ (accessed February 25, 2020).
[36] EPP. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico Magdalena. 2018.
[37] ARCONEL. Proyecto hidroeléctrico Ibarra Fugua n.d. https://www.regulacionelectrica.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-ibarra-fugua/ (accessed February 25, 2020).
[38] ARCONEL. Proyecto hidroeléctrico Sabanilla n.d. https://www.regulacionelectrica.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-sabanilla/ (accessed February 25, 2020).
[39] EPP. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico La Maravilla. 2018.
[40] EPP. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico el Salto. 2018.
[41] MERNNR. Proyecto Hidroeléctrico Quijos. Minist Energy Non-Renewable Natrual Resour n.d. https://www.recursosyenergia.gob.ec/proyecto-hidroelectrico-quijos/ (accessed February 25, 2020).
[42] ELECAUSTRO. Proyecto Múltiple Soldados - Yanuncay 2019. http://www.elecaustro.com.ec/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=64&Itemid=79 (accessed February 25, 2020).
[43] MERNNR. El Aromo Photovoltaic project. Minist Energy Non-Renewable Natrual Resour n.d. http://proyectos.recursosyenergia.gob.ec/aromo.php (accessed February 25, 2020).
[44] MERNNR. Villonaco 2&3 Wind Farm Project n.d. http://proyectos.recursosyenergia.gob.ec/villonaco.php (accessed February 25, 2020).
[45] CELEC. Información Técnica Proyecto Cardenillo 2018. https://www.celec.gob.ec/hidropaute/proyectos/informacion-tecnica-cardenillo.html (accessed February 25, 2020).
[46] CELEC. Información Técnica Proyecto Río Zamora - Santiago 2018. https://www.celec.gob.ec/hidropaute/proyectos/31-espanol/proyectos/index.php (accessed February 25, 2020).
[47] IIGE. Transporte lidera estadísticas de consumo energético en Ecuador. Inst Investig Geológico y Energético, Visión Gub Para El Desarro Del Sect Energía 2018. https://www.geoenergia.gob.ec/transporte-lidera-estadisticas-de-consumo-energetico-en-ecuador/ (accessed February 25, 2020).